By Douglas H. Ginsburg & Koren W. Wong-Ervin*
There is currently confusion in the United States over the proper causation standard under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, with some failing to understand that the default standard (at least in the D.C. Circuit) is the but-for causation standard from the court’s 2008 decision in Rambus v. FTC,1 which is in turn drawn from the analysis in U.S. v Microsoft.2
In Rambus—a Section 2 case the D.C. Circuit decided after its 2001 decision in U.S. v. Microsoft—the court held that the agency failed to prove that “but-for” the defendant’s conduct, there would not have been harm to the competitive process.3 As in Microsoft, the “but-for” world in Rambus was highly uncertain. In both cases, one could reasonably find the defendant’s conduct may have caused the defendant to acquire or maintain its monopoly power. At the same time, it was also possible that the defendants in those cases would have acquired or maintained their monopoly power even absent their anticompetitive behavior. The court in Rambus held the government must bear the burden of that uncertainty. This burden applies as the de facto standard in all Section 2 cases.
One possible argument to the contrary is that Rambus is limited to the specific factual context in which the case arose; specifically, monopolization in the development of a standard involving patents alleged to be essential to that standard. Another argument is that the decision applies somewhat more broadly to cover cases alleging fraud or deception. These arguments are misplaced. For one thing, they ignore the fact that the court itself did not limit its decision, but rather stated:
[T]he Commission expressly limited its theory of liability to Rambus’s unlawful monopolization of four markets in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act. Therefore, we apply principles of antitrust law developed under the Sherman Act.”4
The court found no liability under Section 2 on the ground that the FTC failed to prove that, but for the defendant’s alleged conduct, the defendant would not have acquired monopoly power or been able to exclude rival technologies, thereby allowing it to harm consumers through higher prices. In so holding, the court relied upon the Supreme Court’s decision in NYNEX v. Discon, in which the Court had vacated the lower court’s finding of liability under Sherman Act Sections 1 and 2, explaining that the anticompetitive effects must flow from a “less competitive market” and not “from the exercise of market power that is lawfully in the hands of a monopolist.”5
The argument that a decision applying Section 2 precedent should be narrowly applied to one specific factual context also ignores the Rambus court’s rationale for its holding, which is equally applicable outside the standards-development and fraud or deception contexts. Specifically, the court reasoned that, to apply a different causation standard would risk punishing a lawfully acquired monopoly, for example, one achieved through the creation of a superior technology (or product or service).6 Such conduct (and result) is beyond the reach of U.S. antitrust law.
Click here for a PDF version of the article
* Douglas H. Ginsburg is a judge on the U.S. Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit, Professor of Law and Chairman of the International Board of Advisors to the Global Antitrust Institute at Antonin Scalia Law School, and a former Assistant Attorney General in charge of the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice. Koren W. Wong-Ervin is a Partner at Jones Day, a Senior Fellow at the GW Competition and Innovation Lab, and former enforcer at the U.S. Federal Trade Commission. The views expressed here are the authors’ alone and do not necessarily represent the views of Jones Day or any of its clients. Jones Day represents a number of clients, including Google, that may have an interest in the subject matter of this article. This article was not funded or sponsored. This article draws on the authors’ 2020 article, Challenging Consummated Mergers Under Section 2, Competition Pol’y Int’l (May 2020), https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/05/North-America-Column-May-2020-4-Full.pdf.
1 Rambus Inc. v. FTC, 522 F.3d 456 (D.C. Cir. 2008).
2 United States v. Microsoft, 253 F.3d 34, 58-78 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam).
3 Rambus, 522 F.3d. at 466-67.
4 Id. at 462 (internal citations omitted).
5 NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128, 136 (1998).
6 Id. at 463-64.
Featured News
Electrolux Fined €44.5 Million in French Antitrust Case
Dec 19, 2024 by
CPI
Indian Antitrust Body Raids Alcohol Giants Amid Price Collusion Probe
Dec 19, 2024 by
CPI
Attorneys Seek $525 Million in Fees in NCAA Settlement Case
Dec 19, 2024 by
CPI
Italy’s Competition Watchdog Ends Investigation into Booking.com
Dec 19, 2024 by
CPI
Minnesota Judge Approves $2.4 Million Hormel Settlement in Antitrust Case
Dec 19, 2024 by
CPI
Antitrust Mix by CPI
Antitrust Chronicle® – CRESSE Insights
Dec 19, 2024 by
CPI
Effective Interoperability in Mobile Ecosystems: EU Competition Law Versus Regulation
Dec 19, 2024 by
Giuseppe Colangelo
The Use of Empirical Evidence in Antitrust: Trends, Challenges, and a Path Forward
Dec 19, 2024 by
Eliana Garces
Some Empirical Evidence on the Role of Presumptions and Evidentiary Standards on Antitrust (Under)Enforcement: Is the EC’s New Communication on Art.102 in the Right Direction?
Dec 19, 2024 by
Yannis Katsoulacos
The EC’s Draft Guidelines on the Application of Article 102 TFEU: An Economic Perspective
Dec 19, 2024 by
Benoit Durand